From: [c--am--r] at [optilink.COM] (Clayton Cramer)
Newsgroups: alt.news-media,misc.legal,talk.politics.misc
Subject: Re: Waco Coverup Evidence (videotape)
Date: 24 Aug 93 00:06:00 GMT

Here's the article, in the form that it appeared in the San
Jose Mercury-News recently.  The references to the figures,
of course, don't mean anything, because I can't turn the neat
little graphs into ASCII.  See the table at the end from which
the charts were drawn:

    CALIFORNIA'S HANDGUN WAITING PERIOD LAW, 1952-1990:
                        DID IT WORK?



How effective  are handgun  waiting  periods  in  preventing
murder?  *Do they decrease the murder rate?*  Since a national
waiting period  for handgun  purchases has  been touted as a
possible  solution   to  America's  murder  problem,  it  is
appropriate to  examine how  such waiting  period laws  have
actually worked.

Unfortunately,  we   don't  have  the  option  of  comparing
equivalent populations,  one with  waiting periods,  and one
without,  for  the  simple  reason  that  the  factors  that
determine murder  rates are  not perfectly  understood.  The
best we  can hope for is to examine the year to year changes
in murder rates before and after a waiting period is created
or extended.

In much  the same  way that  the  populations  of  adjoining
states are  not exactly  comparable, the  demographics of  a
state change  from year  to year.   But while the population
characteristics of  two adjoining states may be dramatically
different in  subtle and  unobvious ways,  the  demographics
*within* a  state change  very slowly  from year  to year,  as
people age,  change their behavior, or move in or out of the
state.   As a  consequence, while looking at a state's crime
rates through time is still a technique with limitations, it
is nowhere near as prone to problems of non-comparability as
comparing different states.

What result  should we  expect a  waiting  period  to  have?
There are  two purposes  usually given  for firearms waiting
periods: time for a background check on the purchaser; and a
"cooling off"  period, while  passions abate.    As  instant
background checks become feasible, and the waiting period is
no longer  needed for  that  purpose,  the  argument  for  a
handgun waiting  period relies  on the  claim  that  waiting
periods save lives because of the "cooling off" of passions.
What evidence  does California's experience provide to judge
the accuracy of such a statement?

California is  very nearly a perfect example of a laboratory
for waiting  period laws.  California is sufficiently large,
and its  urban populations  are so  remote from  its borders
with adjoining states, that a waiting period is enforced not
only by  state law, but also by the limits of geography.  In
addition to  the Gun  Control Act  of 1968, which prohibited
interstate purchases  of  handguns,[1]  most  of  California's
murders happen  in a small number of urban counties that are
at least  six to eight hours driving time from other states.
Even assuming  that a seller could be found *immediately* over
the border  in Nevada,  Oregon, or Arizona, willing to break
federal law, the travel time alone imposes a waiting period.

California has  also had  a waiting period for handgun sales
since at  least 1923.   The California Legislature increased
the handgun  waiting period  from one to three days in 1955,
to five  days in  1965, and to the current 15 days in 1975.[2]
Figure 1,  "California  Handgun  Waiting  Periods  &  Murder
Rates" plots the murder rate per 100,000 Californians during
the period  1952 through  1990.[3]  (The use of a murder *rate*,
which counts murders relative to the size of the population,
eliminates changes  in  the  number  of  murders  caused  by
changes in the number of people living in California.)

The increase  from one to three days in 1955, and from three
to five  days in  1965, had  no apparent  effect  on  rising
murder rates.   Indeed, the California murder rate went from
a bit  above 2/100,000 people in 1952, to over 10/100,000 by
1975.   While it  is certainly  true that  murder rates rose
throughout the United States during this period, as Figure 1
shows, California's  murder rate  rose *even  faster* than the
murder rate for the rest of the United States.

The first full year of the fifteen day waiting period, 1976,
showed  a   1%  decline   in  murder  rates  -  followed  by
continually rising  murder rates, peaking in 1980.  In fact,
murder rates  didn't start  to decline until 1981, five full
years after  the new  waiting period  took effect.   Can the
advocates of  waiting periods  take heart from the fact that
California's murder rates *eventually* fell?

No.   Murder rates  in the rest of the United States roughly
rise and  fall in parallel with the California murder rates.
Indeed, there  is a  0.93 correlation between the California
murder rate,  and the murder rate for the rest of the United
States -- astonishingly high.   From 1974 onward, the strong
similarity in  these curves suggests that factors beyond the
reach of  California's laws  were by  far the most important
determiner of  California's murder  rate.    The  California
murder rate  fell 36% from 1980 to 1985, but the murder rate
for the  rest  of  the  U.S.  (the  U.S.  murder  rate  with
California's population and murders removed) fell 26% during
the same period.[4]

In much  the same  way, the  murder rate for the rest of the
U.S. rose 13% from 1985 to 1990; during the same period, the
California murder  rate also  rose 13%.   In  both cases,  a
small  "hump"  of  murders  appeared  in  1986,  there  were
declines in 1987 and 1988, then the murder rate increased in
1989 and  1990.   Indeed, where California murder rates were
always *lower*  than for  the rest of the United States before
the 15  day waiting period took effect in 1976, California's
murder rate  from 1976 onward was always *higher* than for the
rest of the United States.

What conclusions  can we  reach from  the  data?    Positive
correlation (that  two  events  happen  together  with  high
frequency) does  not prove  causality (that one event causes
the other  event).   As an  example, higher  ice cream  cone
sales are  positively correlated with increased rape rates -
but this  doesn't mean that ice cream cone sales cause rape.
Rather, one  underlying cause  of both  ice cream cone sales
and rape  is hot weather.  (It is *probably* because there are
more unlocked  windows in  the hot  summer months,  allowing
easier access  to victims  at home).   It  is also true that
zero  correlation  between  two  events  does  not  *disprove*
causality -- but if  no correlation  (positive or  negative)
between two events can be shown, it should certainly make us
skeptical that a causal relationship exists.

There are  a number  of possibilities that might explain the
astonishingly high  0.91 correlation between handgun waiting
periods and murder rates in California:

1. Waiting  periods may  be completely  useless for reducing
murder rates.   This  doesn't mean  that  a  waiting  period
doesn't *occasionally*  prevent a murder from happening; there
are probably cases where delay may cause reflection, and the
passions of  the moment  may  subside.    So  what  are  the
circumstances that would cancel out the murders prevented by
a waiting period?

  +  For every murder thus prevented, a victim was similarly
     prevented from buying a handgun for self-defense.

  +  That so-called  "crimes of  passion"  are  not  readily
     deterred by  waiting periods because of substitution of
     other weapons.

  +  That murderers  are already  armed,  and  thus  waiting
     periods do not delay them.

  +  That murderers don't bother buying handguns legally.

2. Waiting  periods may  be  of  some  limited  utility  for
reducing  murder   rates,  but  were  overwhelmed  by  other
factors.

3. Waiting periods may *increase* murder rates, but the effect
that we  see may  have been caused by other factors, and the
waiting period made only a minor contribution.

4. Waiting periods may increase murder rates, and the effect
was dramatic enough to explain what we see.

5. Waiting  periods may  be ineffective,  and the  political
energy devoted  to them (both in support and in opposition),
meant that  more effective  strategies for  reducing  murder
simply  fell  by  the  wayside,  and  the  murder  rate  was
unaffected.

Unfortunately, it  is impossible,  based  on  the  available
data, to  determine which  of these  five  possibilities  is
correct.   In a sense, though, it doesn't really much matter
which of  these propositions  is the answer to the question.
If possibility #2 above (the most positive interpretation of
the data  for advocates of handgun waiting periods) is true,
the  effectiveness  of  handgun  waiting  periods  as  *crime
control* is so slight that it doesn't jump out at us from the
data.   The political energy devoted to waiting periods thus
makes no  sense --  especially since opposition to the Brady
Bill centers  on the  waiting  period  aspect  of  the  law.
(Contrary  to   popular  perceptions,   the  National  Rifle
Association has  supported,  and  continues  to  reluctantly
support an instant background check law as an alternative to
a national  waiting period.   Their support for such laws is
reluctant, partly  because of skepticism that *any* background
check law  is going  to  solve  the  fundamental  causes  of
violence in our society.)

The most  plausible explanation for the continued popularity
of waiting  periods for  gun purchase,  in  spite  of  their
ineffectiveness, is  that they  represent a  cheap consensus
among politicians.   A  major division exists in our society
about the best method for solving the problems of murder and
other violent  crimes.  Conservatives generally favor longer
sentences for violent felonies.  This requires more prisons;
prisons cost  money.  Liberals generally favor more spending
on welfare  programs and  education as  a method of reducing
violent crime;  these aren't cheap, either.  Politicians are
reluctant to anger taxpayers by use of either strategy.  But
creating  and   lengthening  waiting   periods  for  handgun
purchase, because  they require  no  expenditure  of  public
funds, are  an especially tempting "solution" to the violent
crime problem  - even  when the  evidence suggests that they
are *at  best*, of  only minor value, and at worst, completely
ineffective.

======================================================================
Clayton  E.   Cramer  is   a  software   engineer   with   a
telecommunications manufacturer in Northern California.  His
first book,  _By The  Dim And  Flaring Lamps:  The Civil  War
Diary of  Samuel McIlvaine_,  was published in 1990.  Research 
assistance for this article was provided by Charles R. Hardy.


Notes
  [1] 18 USC sec. 922.
  [2] Cal. Penal Code Ann.  12071 (1991).
  [3] California murder rates for 1952-1989 in this article
come from California Dept. of Justice, _Crimes Reported,
1952-1989, Number and Rate per 100,000 Population_.
California murder rates for 1990 are from California Dept.
of Justice, _California Criminal Justice Profile 1990_, 5.
U.S. murder rates were derived from population and raw
murder figures in FBI _Uniform Crime Reports for the United
States_, 1952-1990.
  [4] This is an important distinction, because California's
population is large enough, especially in the latter part of
the period studied, that its murders significantly influence
the U.S. murder rate.  Hence, throughout this article, we
are comparing the California murder rate, with the murder
rate of the U.S. minus California.

Year,Waiting Period (in days),California Murder Rate,US - Cal. Murder Rate
'52,1,2.40,4.75
'53,1,2.28,4.62
'54,1,3.33,4.28
'55,1,3.20,4.21
'56,3,3.49,4.18
'57,3,3.50,4.77
'58,3,3.71,4.77
'59,3,3.37,4.96
'60,3,3.91,5.17
'61,3,3.70,4.78
'62,3,3.94,4.56
'63,3,3.71,4.57
'64,3,4.16,4.89
'65,3,4.76,5.10
'66,5,4.69,5.65
'67,5,5.40,6.16
'68,5,5.99,6.89
'69,5,6.93,7.23
'70,5,6.76,7.81
'71,5,8.03,8.54
'72,5,8.69,8.84
'73,5,8.92,9.24
'74,5,9.30,9.67
'75,5,10.20,9.42
'76,15,10.09,8.45
'77,15,11.10,8.41
'78,15,11.39,8.49
'79,15,12.65,9.17
'80,15,14.33,9.63
'81,15,12.98,9.42
'82,15,11.24,8.79
'83,15,10.49,7.97
'84,15,10.63,7.58
'85,15,10.55,7.64
'86,15,11.23,8.23
'87,15,10.59,7.98
'88,15,10.41,8.18
'89,15,10.87,8.40
'90,15,11.88,9.03


-- 
Clayton E. Cramer {uunet,pyramid}!optilink!cramer  My opinions, all mine!
Anyone that calls what comes out of a third trimester abortion "fetal tissue"
and not a baby, needs some glasses.
Newsgroups: alt.news-media,alt.society.civil-liberty,misc.legal,talk.politics.guns,talk.politics.misc
Subject: Re: Waco Coverup Evidence (videotape)
Summary: 
Expires: 
References: <24h758$[d 6 u] at [paperboy.osf.org]> <[1993 Aug 20 113910 19891] at [lds.loral.com]> <252pt5$[s n v] at [transfer.stratus.com]>
Sender: 
Followup-To: 
Distribution: 
Organization: DSC/Optilink Access Products
Keywords: guns, stupidity, whacko

In article <252pt5$[s n v] at [transfer.stratus.com]> [c d t] at [sw.stratus.com] (C. D. Tavares) writes:
>In article <[1993 Aug 20 113910 19891] at [lds.loral.com]>, [k--d--l] at [lds.loral.com] (Colin Kendall 6842) writes:
>> The best way to find out whether gun contol works would be to find
>> groups of identical cities, and enact gun control in some of them and
>> not others, and observe the results. Unfortunately, there are no
>> identical cities.
>
>Uh, there sure are.  They're the same city, before and after gun control.
>
>Try comparing their own crime rates with their own crime rates, before
>and after.  And for a lark, try comparing that change with the change
>in the crime rates in surrounding areas and on a national basis.  The
>comparison will give you pause.  
>
>Clayton Cramer published such a comparison for the state of California 
>in a recent issue of American Rifleman.  It showed a drastic jump in 
>the crime rates AFTER every increase in the California waiting period,
>until the California rate was something like 15(?) times the rate of 
>the surrounding areas.  Maybe somebody has it online here.

Here's the article, in the form that it appeared in the San
Jose Mercury-News recently.  The references to the figures,
of course, don't mean anything, because I can't turn the neat
little graphs into ASCII.  See the table at the end from which
the charts were drawn:

    CALIFORNIA'S HANDGUN WAITING PERIOD LAW, 1952-1990:
                        DID IT WORK?



How effective  are handgun  waiting  periods  in  preventing
murder?  *Do they decrease the murder rate?*  Since a national
waiting period  for handgun  purchases has  been touted as a
possible  solution   to  America's  murder  problem,  it  is
appropriate to  examine how  such waiting  period laws  have
actually worked.

Unfortunately,  we   don't  have  the  option  of  comparing
equivalent populations,  one with  waiting periods,  and one
without,  for  the  simple  reason  that  the  factors  that
determine murder  rates are  not perfectly  understood.  The
best we  can hope for is to examine the year to year changes
in murder rates before and after a waiting period is created
or extended.

In much  the same  way that  the  populations  of  adjoining
states are  not exactly  comparable, the  demographics of  a
state change  from year  to year.   But while the population
characteristics of  two adjoining states may be dramatically
different in  subtle and  unobvious ways,  the  demographics
*within* a  state change  very slowly  from year  to year,  as
people age,  change their behavior, or move in or out of the
state.   As a  consequence, while looking at a state's crime
rates through time is still a technique with limitations, it
is nowhere near as prone to problems of non-comparability as
comparing different states.

What result  should we  expect a  waiting  period  to  have?
There are  two purposes  usually given  for firearms waiting
periods: time for a background check on the purchaser; and a
"cooling off"  period, while  passions abate.    As  instant
background checks become feasible, and the waiting period is
no longer  needed for  that  purpose,  the  argument  for  a
handgun waiting  period relies  on the  claim  that  waiting
periods save lives because of the "cooling off" of passions.
What evidence  does California's experience provide to judge
the accuracy of such a statement?

California is  very nearly a perfect example of a laboratory
for waiting  period laws.  California is sufficiently large,
and its  urban populations  are so  remote from  its borders
with adjoining states, that a waiting period is enforced not
only by  state law, but also by the limits of geography.  In
addition to  the Gun  Control Act  of 1968, which prohibited
interstate purchases  of  handguns,[1]  most  of  California's
murders happen  in a small number of urban counties that are
at least  six to eight hours driving time from other states.
Even assuming  that a seller could be found *immediately* over
the border  in Nevada,  Oregon, or Arizona, willing to break
federal law, the travel time alone imposes a waiting period.

California has  also had  a waiting period for handgun sales
since at  least 1923.   The California Legislature increased
the handgun  waiting period  from one to three days in 1955,
to five  days in  1965, and to the current 15 days in 1975.[2]
Figure 1,  "California  Handgun  Waiting  Periods  &  Murder
Rates" plots the murder rate per 100,000 Californians during
the period  1952 through  1990.[3]  (The use of a murder *rate*,
which counts murders relative to the size of the population,
eliminates changes  in  the  number  of  murders  caused  by
changes in the number of people living in California.)

The increase  from one to three days in 1955, and from three
to five  days in  1965, had  no apparent  effect  on  rising
murder rates.   Indeed, the California murder rate went from
a bit  above 2/100,000 people in 1952, to over 10/100,000 by
1975.   While it  is certainly  true that  murder rates rose
throughout the United States during this period, as Figure 1
shows, California's  murder rate  rose *even  faster* than the
murder rate for the rest of the United States.

The first full year of the fifteen day waiting period, 1976,
showed  a   1%  decline   in  murder  rates  -  followed  by
continually rising  murder rates, peaking in 1980.  In fact,
murder rates  didn't start  to decline until 1981, five full
years after  the new  waiting period  took effect.   Can the
advocates of  waiting periods  take heart from the fact that
California's murder rates *eventually* fell?

No.   Murder rates  in the rest of the United States roughly
rise and  fall in parallel with the California murder rates.
Indeed, there  is a  0.93 correlation between the California
murder rate,  and the murder rate for the rest of the United
States -- astonishingly high.   From 1974 onward, the strong
similarity in  these curves suggests that factors beyond the
reach of  California's laws  were by  far the most important
determiner of  California's murder  rate.    The  California
murder rate  fell 36% from 1980 to 1985, but the murder rate
for the  rest  of  the  U.S.  (the  U.S.  murder  rate  with
California's population and murders removed) fell 26% during
the same period.[4]

In much  the same  way, the  murder rate for the rest of the
U.S. rose 13% from 1985 to 1990; during the same period, the
California murder  rate also  rose 13%.   In  both cases,  a
small  "hump"  of  murders  appeared  in  1986,  there  were
declines in 1987 and 1988, then the murder rate increased in
1989 and  1990.   Indeed, where California murder rates were
always *lower*  than for  the rest of the United States before
the 15  day waiting period took effect in 1976, California's
murder rate  from 1976 onward was always *higher* than for the
rest of the United States.

What conclusions  can we  reach from  the  data?    Positive
correlation (that  two  events  happen  together  with  high
frequency) does  not prove  causality (that one event causes
the other  event).   As an  example, higher  ice cream  cone
sales are  positively correlated with increased rape rates -
but this  doesn't mean that ice cream cone sales cause rape.
Rather, one  underlying cause  of both  ice cream cone sales
and rape  is hot weather.  (It is *probably* because there are
more unlocked  windows in  the hot  summer months,  allowing
easier access  to victims  at home).   It  is also true that
zero  correlation  between  two  events  does  not  *disprove*
causality -- but if  no correlation  (positive or  negative)
between two events can be shown, it should certainly make us
skeptical that a causal relationship exists.

There are  a number  of possibilities that might explain the
astonishingly high  0.91 correlation between handgun waiting
periods and murder rates in California:

1. Waiting  periods may  be completely  useless for reducing
murder rates.   This  doesn't mean  that  a  waiting  period
doesn't *occasionally*  prevent a murder from happening; there
are probably cases where delay may cause reflection, and the
passions of  the moment  may  subside.    So  what  are  the
circumstances that would cancel out the murders prevented by
a waiting period?

  +  For every murder thus prevented, a victim was similarly
     prevented from buying a handgun for self-defense.

  +  That so-called  "crimes of  passion"  are  not  readily
     deterred by  waiting periods because of substitution of
     other weapons.

  +  That murderers  are already  armed,  and  thus  waiting
     periods do not delay them.

  +  That murderers don't bother buying handguns legally.

2. Waiting  periods may  be  of  some  limited  utility  for
reducing  murder   rates,  but  were  overwhelmed  by  other
factors.

3. Waiting periods may *increase* murder rates, but the effect
that we  see may  have been caused by other factors, and the
waiting period made only a minor contribution.

4. Waiting periods may increase murder rates, and the effect
was dramatic enough to explain what we see.

5. Waiting  periods may  be ineffective,  and the  political
energy devoted  to them (both in support and in opposition),
meant that  more effective  strategies for  reducing  murder
simply  fell  by  the  wayside,  and  the  murder  rate  was
unaffected.

Unfortunately, it  is impossible,  based  on  the  available
data, to  determine which  of these  five  possibilities  is
correct.   In a sense, though, it doesn't really much matter
which of  these propositions  is the answer to the question.
If possibility #2 above (the most positive interpretation of
the data  for advocates of handgun waiting periods) is true,
the  effectiveness  of  handgun  waiting  periods  as  *crime
control* is so slight that it doesn't jump out at us from the
data.   The political energy devoted to waiting periods thus
makes no  sense --  especially since opposition to the Brady
Bill centers  on the  waiting  period  aspect  of  the  law.
(Contrary  to   popular  perceptions,   the  National  Rifle
Association has  supported,  and  continues  to  reluctantly
support an instant background check law as an alternative to
a national  waiting period.   Their support for such laws is
reluctant, partly  because of skepticism that *any* background
check law  is going  to  solve  the  fundamental  causes  of
violence in our society.)

The most  plausible explanation for the continued popularity
of waiting  periods for  gun purchase,  in  spite  of  their
ineffectiveness, is  that they  represent a  cheap consensus
among politicians.   A  major division exists in our society
about the best method for solving the problems of murder and
other violent  crimes.  Conservatives generally favor longer
sentences for violent felonies.  This requires more prisons;
prisons cost  money.  Liberals generally favor more spending
on welfare  programs and  education as  a method of reducing
violent crime;  these aren't cheap, either.  Politicians are
reluctant to anger taxpayers by use of either strategy.  But
creating  and   lengthening  waiting   periods  for  handgun
purchase, because  they require  no  expenditure  of  public
funds, are  an especially tempting "solution" to the violent
crime problem  - even  when the  evidence suggests that they
are *at  best*, of  only minor value, and at worst, completely
ineffective.

======================================================================
Clayton  E.   Cramer  is   a  software   engineer   with   a
telecommunications manufacturer in Northern California.  His
first book,  _By The  Dim And  Flaring Lamps:  The Civil  War
Diary of  Samuel McIlvaine_,  was published in 1990.  Research 
assistance for this article was provided by Charles R. Hardy.


Notes
  [1] 18 USC sec. 922.
  [2] Cal. Penal Code Ann.  12071 (1991).
  [3] California murder rates for 1952-1989 in this article
come from California Dept. of Justice, _Crimes Reported,
1952-1989, Number and Rate per 100,000 Population_.
California murder rates for 1990 are from California Dept.
of Justice, _California Criminal Justice Profile 1990_, 5.
U.S. murder rates were derived from population and raw
murder figures in FBI _Uniform Crime Reports for the United
States_, 1952-1990.
  [4] This is an important distinction, because California's
population is large enough, especially in the latter part of
the period studied, that its murders significantly influence
the U.S. murder rate.  Hence, throughout this article, we
are comparing the California murder rate, with the murder
rate of the U.S. minus California.

Year,Waiting Period (in days),California Murder Rate,US - Cal. Murder Rate
'52,1,2.40,4.75
'53,1,2.28,4.62
'54,1,3.33,4.28
'55,1,3.20,4.21
'56,3,3.49,4.18
'57,3,3.50,4.77
'58,3,3.71,4.77
'59,3,3.37,4.96
'60,3,3.91,5.17
'61,3,3.70,4.78
'62,3,3.94,4.56
'63,3,3.71,4.57
'64,3,4.16,4.89
'65,3,4.76,5.10
'66,5,4.69,5.65
'67,5,5.40,6.16
'68,5,5.99,6.89
'69,5,6.93,7.23
'70,5,6.76,7.81
'71,5,8.03,8.54
'72,5,8.69,8.84
'73,5,8.92,9.24
'74,5,9.30,9.67
'75,5,10.20,9.42
'76,15,10.09,8.45
'77,15,11.10,8.41
'78,15,11.39,8.49
'79,15,12.65,9.17
'80,15,14.33,9.63
'81,15,12.98,9.42
'82,15,11.24,8.79
'83,15,10.49,7.97
'84,15,10.63,7.58
'85,15,10.55,7.64
'86,15,11.23,8.23
'87,15,10.59,7.98
'88,15,10.41,8.18
'89,15,10.87,8.40
'90,15,11.88,9.03


Newsgroups: alt.news-media,alt.society.civil-liberty,misc.legal,talk.politics.guns,talk.politics.misc
Subject: Re: Waco Coverup Evidence (videotape)
Summary: 
Expires: 
References: <24h758$[d 6 u] at [paperboy.osf.org]> <[1993 Aug 20 113910 19891] at [lds.loral.com]> <252pt5$[s n v] at [transfer.stratus.com]>
Sender: 
Followup-To: 
Distribution: 
Organization: DSC/Optilink Access Products
Keywords: guns, stupidity, whacko

In article <252pt5$[s n v] at [transfer.stratus.com]> [c d t] at [sw.stratus.com] (C. D. Tavares) writes:
>In article <[1993 Aug 20 113910 19891] at [lds.loral.com]>, [k--d--l] at [lds.loral.com] (Colin Kendall 6842) writes:
>
>> Even if one could show a significant drop in gun crime *after* passing
>> such laws, it would still be meaningless, since it still wouldn't show
>> any kind of causation. Just as when the pro-gun people point to New
>> York or D.C. and say that gun control laws were passed and gun crime
>> subsequently increased, and triumphantly proclaim that the former is
>> the *cause* of the latter. This is a well-known logical fallacy. It's
>> called 'post hoc ergo propter hoc', meaning 'after this, therefore
>> because of this'.
>
>> Look. New York and D.C. had a problem with gun crime. It was
>> increasing.  In an attempt to curb it, people passed gun control laws.
>> Gun crime continued to increase. This is not to say that if gun control
>> laws had not been passed, gun crime would have increased faster, or
>> more slowly, or stayed the same. Nobody knows.
>
>> It may be the case that if gun control laws had not been passed, things
>> would have gotten worse even faster. Nobody knows.
>
>Bullshit.  So prove it's a logical fallacy.  Find somewhere where they
>were having the same problem, passed gun control laws, and the problem
>got BETTER.
>
>You can't, because there ARE NONE.  Not England, not Canada, not France.
>Cerainly not Mexico, Jamaica, or Ireland.
>
>Yet you point to NYC, DC, Chicago, L.A., say "causation is not proved,"
>as an attempt to imply that the strong correlation is therefore irrelevant.
>
>Do you work for a tobacco company, Mr. Kendall?  
>
>(Hey, wasn't there a cigarette called "Loral?")
>
>> It may be the case that if gun control laws had not been passed, people
>> would have become angry and armed themselves and shot more criminals,
>> thus leading to a decrease in gun crime.  Nobody knows.
>
>"Although shootings of criminals represent a small fraction of defensive uses
>of guns, Americans shoot criminals with a frequency that must be regarded as
>remarkable by any standard." ("Crime Control through the Private Use of
>Armed Force" Professor Gary Kleck, 2/88 *Social Problems*.)  Dr. Kleck 
>estimates that annually, "gun-wielding civilians in self-defense or some 
>other legally justified cause" kill at least 1,500 felons, or 2.5 times as 
>many as are shot dead by the police.
>
>And that's with the CURRENT laws.
>
>> The best way to find out whether gun contol works would be to find
>> groups of identical cities, and enact gun control in some of them and
>> not others, and observe the results. Unfortunately, there are no
>> identical cities.
>
>Uh, there sure are.  They're the same city, before and after gun control.
>
>Try comparing their own crime rates with their own crime rates, before
>and after.  And for a lark, try comparing that change with the change
>in the crime rates in surrounding areas and on a national basis.  The
>comparison will give you pause.  
>
>Clayton Cramer published such a comparison for the state of California 
>in a recent issue of American Rifleman.  It showed a drastic jump in 
>the crime rates AFTER every increase in the California waiting period,
>until the California rate was something like 15(?) times the rate of 
>the surrounding areas.  Maybe somebody has it online here.
>
>But don't let US "pick" the cases.  Why trust us?  You pick one, and 
>do your own unbiased study.  We'll wait.
>
>> The next best way would be to use groups of *similar* cities. But
>> I fear that in this case, whichever side was disappointed as a 
>> result of the study would just say, "Oh, well, you really can't
>> compare city X and city Y, the demographics are so different...".
>
>Try the same city or state, and try finding one that REMOVED some gun 
>controls.  Try the states of Mississippi or Florida, which recently
>introduced concealed carry for citizens.  Try the city of Orlando,
>which publicly armed women against rape.  Try Isleton, California.
>Try the city of Kennesaw, Georgia.  Compare their violent crime 
>rates before and after the change.  
>
>Find one where the rates went UP.
>
>Find one where the change rate in the affected area DIDN'T compare 
>favorably to that of the surrounding areas in the subsequent period.
>-- 
>
>[c d t] at [rocket.sw.stratus.com]   --If you believe that I speak for my company,
>OR [c d t] at [vos.stratus.com]        write today for my special Investors' Packet...


-- 
Clayton E. Cramer {uunet,pyramid}!optilink!cramer  My opinions, all mine!
Anyone that calls what comes out of a third trimester abortion "fetal tissue"
and not a baby, needs some glasses.