Economies of scale and government-run health care
One of the common arguments in favor of government takeovers of a service is that government agencies can perform the service cheaper because of “economies of scale”.
Since insurance is a requirement… more premiums should bring the price down.
This argument shows a profound misunderstanding of what an economy of scale is and how scaling up works to raise the quality of a service or product while also bringing the price down.1
More premiums, like more of any service, only bring prices down when people are free to buy or not to buy, and when buyers are free to negotiate with sellers for what they want to buy and what they are willing to pay for it. The ACA, for example, mandates what people are required to buy within very narrow boundaries, and mandates that they must in fact buy it (or pay a penalty). This is guaranteed to cause prices to rise drastically. The skyrocketing prices and reduced access to health care providers that we now see was predicted during the law’s passage based on that simple economic principle.
Economies of scale only work when they allow a leaner competitor to discover a way to provide the same or better service at a cheaper price.2 An economy of scale doesn’t automatically cause the same old processes by the same old business or government agency to suddenly become cheaper. If anything, large scale in a monopoly will cause prices to rise and quality to drop as competition moves from competing to reach more people and persuade them to purchase the service, to instead competing for turf inside the bureaucracy.
This shift to bureaucratic infighting causes increased prices to pay for the extra soldiers in the turf war; and it causes lower quality service as the employees turn inward and pay more attention to the bureaucracy than to their customers. Why shouldn’t they? Their customers have no choice.
But even worse, increased scale in a government or government-created monopoly also results in increased complexity for the people who need the service. The inevitable turf wars mean that individual services become spread across multiple departments, any one of which can block or delay service—such as some person’s needed health care. Navigating the system becomes an essential skill, and it is one that people with more resources—who can hire dedicated navigators—will do better at than people with fewer resources.
For a long time, the greatest example of government-run health care in the United States, often praised in the mailings I received from progressive lobbyists, was the Veterans Administration. And they were right, although I haven’t seen that example used as often now that the VA’s efforts to kill veterans has been made public.3
Government agencies don’t have competitors who can put them out of business, which is why you never hear of “lean government agencies” except sarcastically or as an aspirational item during campaigns.
Government monopolies, such as single-payer bureaucracies, have even less incentive than government-created private monopolies to take advantage of economies of scale to improve quality and reduce prices. Very often, if not always, government agencies are able to hide their costs outside of direct charges to the recipient of the service, or even indirect charges through tax appropriations. Costs can be offloaded to civil services, government equipment providers, government office space providers, government pension providers, and more I’m not devious enough to think of. Government agencies can even make the rules about what counts as a cost to be recorded against them—which is why pensions are often excluded from the cost of government-run services4. Private monopolies don’t usually get to do this.
The Unaffordable Care Act tried to provide this same ability to insurance companies by including a “risk corridor” that used taxes to bail out insurance companies who spent more than they received from their customers. Of course, the risk corridor increased costs because it had to pay for the bureaucrats to manage the risk corridor on both sides of the bailout. But it also means subsidizing poor customer service within each insurance company. When the taxpayer is going to secretly bail you out, what does it matter that you’ve made health care so complicated and bureaucrat-heavy that even an insurance company can’t afford it?
Economies of scale also require a competitive environment to improve the quality of a service. More eyes on a problem all trying to steal the other’s customers are what drove the rapid increase in quality of care we have often seen in this country. A single government-run organization has no such incentive, and in fact has the opposite incentive. All of those quality improvements initially cost more money to perform. They won’t be improved without competition because they violate the cost-cutting provisions government systems impose in order to pretend to the benefits of a free market.
Such as the exchanges that Democrats love to put in place to emulate a free market but that inevitably cause higher prices and service blackouts.
So when someone says that health care should not be profit-oriented, should not be a business, what they really mean is that health care businesses should not have to compete for your business, on either quality or price. What they really mean is that it should be expensive, low quality, and so complicated that only the rich and well-connected can take advantage of it.
In response to Why we must not ration health care: Rationing health care means fewer cures.
It also contradicts their other go-to claim that the service should not be treated as a business! In fact, pointing out that economies of scale only work when there is competition usually brings exactly that contradictory response, for example, “I don’t care… There is nothing you can say to change my mind that Healthcare does not need to be a money making industry.”
↑For products economies of scale can sometimes produce lower costs to the company making the product, however, even then those lower costs are likely to be more than offset by increased bureaucracy absent a competitor to keep them honest.
↑At a recent science fiction convention, I talked to a veteran wearing a t-shirt that read “The VA: giving veterans a second chance to die for their country since 1930.”
↑Or are estimated using impossibly-high interest rates that make the pension look like an asset rather than a cost.
↑
bailout
- Another Illegal Obamacare Bailout Appears to Be on the Way: Chris Jacobs at National Review Online
- “As with most things Obamacare, risk corridors haven’t turned out quite like the administration promised. In 2014, insurers paid in a total of $362 million into the risk-corridor program—but requested $2.87 billion in disbursements.”
- Congress must continue blocking ‘risk corridor’ bailout of insurance companies: Jim Jordan at The Hill
- “Taxpayers should not be forced to bail out any corporations that lose money, especially those getting so many government benefits already.”
- Large Bailout for ACA Insurers May Be Coming: Brian Blase at Mercatus Center
- “Average premium increases above 25%, roughly one-third of U.S. counties projected to lack any competition in the Affordable Care Act (ACA) exchanges next year, and enrollment less than half of initial expectations provide strong evidence that the law’s exchange program is failing. Moreover, the failure is occurring despite massive government subsidies, including nearly $15 billion of unlawful payments, for participating insurers.”
government monopolies
- The Bureaucracy Event Horizon
- Government bureaucracy is the ultimate broken window.
- Charlie Gard’s Case Shows Why Government Should Stay Out of End-of-Life Choices: Scott Shackford at Reason Magazine
- “Charlie Gard, an infant with a serious and rare genetic condition and significant brain damage, is terminally ill. His parents would like to pursue an experimental treatment in the United States. Doctors, granted authority by the British government and their socialized medical system, have told them no. They are ordering that Gard's life support be shut down.”
- Exchanging the market for high prices and corruption
- The Democratic health insurance exchange looks like it’s going to make many of the same mistakes politicians made in California when they tried to choke electrical power through a power exchange.
- Trump Tweets Out Support for Charlie Gard; Media Refuses to Mention: Ace at Ace of Spades HQ
- “If we can help little #CharlieGard, as per our friends in the U.K. and the Pope, we would be delighted to do so.”
More economies of scale
- Growth does not pay for itself
- Growth that doesn’t pay for itself is cancerous growth. It isn’t the growth of population that gets more expensive, but the expanding grasp of government.
- California never had a free market power failure
- California’s experiment in free market power generation has become mythological in how it is remembered. The left is desperate to tar it as a free market failure. But California’s experiment wasn’t free market. It was a massive government-managed exchange practically designed to cause high prices.
- Why don’t taxes go down when population goes up?
- The left says that government can better take advantage of economies of scale. So why don’t they lower taxes when population rises?
More government monopolies
- Deadly complications of government bureaucracy
- Government monopolies, whether government agencies or de facto government agencies in the form of government-sponsored enterprises, aren’t rewarded by getting product to the people who need it. They’re rewarded by kissing up the bureaucratic chain.
- COVID Lessons: How can we respond to a disease before it spreads?
- How can we make ourselves less vulnerable to sudden epidemics, before they become epidemics, and without causing epidemic levels of deaths?
- COVID Lessons: Government Monopolies are Still Monopolies
- Our response to COVID-19 was almost designed to make it worse. We shut down the nimble small businesses that could respond quickly, and relied almost solely on large corporations and the government monopolies that failed us, because they are monopolies.
- A free market in union representation
- Every monopoly is said to be special, that this monopoly is necessary. And yet every time, getting rid of the monopoly improves service, quality, and price. There is no reason for unions to be any different.
- Why is it so difficult to hold schools accountable?
- Simulating accountability in education has the same problems as simulating accountability in health care or any other monopoly. Tests and grades and paperwork are never as effective as choice.
- Two more pages with the topic government monopolies, and other related pages
More ObamaCare
- Community health acts to improve Obamacare
- Democrats now want to talk about how to improve Obamacare. Here’s how to do it.
- Democrat Chris Murphy: Obamacare is “the end of health care”
- From the mouths of hypocrites, comes wisdom. It’s almost biblical.
- Health insurance reform? What health insurance reform?
- The Truth About Republicans: they don’t want to repeal Obamacare.
- A tale of two negotiators
- If you want to see how Republicans in Congress fail to pass successful reforms, compare the House Obamacare “repeal” with the White House’s budget.
- Election lessons: Obamacare and how compromise works
- As Republicans work into 2017, they need to learn how negotiations and compromise work. President Trump may not be the best teacher, but he at least understands how to negotiate.
- 16 more pages with the topic ObamaCare, and other related pages